Defending the Gunslinger

GunslingerJoburg

By Gareth B

‘Gunslinger’ typically refers to the men of the Old West who gained a reputation for being skilled and dangerous with a gun. Among the ranks of these popular legends are outlaws and lawmen alike, although we know today that the line between this dichotomy was often blurred, hence the enduring reputation of the gunslinger as an unpredictable and wily opportunist.

For the purposes of this article, however, I use ‘gunslinger’ to refer to an armed man who offers the service of his presence and skills to protect a client’s material interests.

The Old West was no country for unarmed men, if Hollywood is to be believed. All manner of disputes, from accusations of cattle-rustling and card-sharking to infidelity and the simple bar brawl, would be settled in the street with a guns-drawn duel. Reality, however, is far more banal and the “Wild” West was as orderly, if not more so, than contemporary society. The mythos of anarchic chaos prevailing during this period of history most likely arises from popular legends surrounding the gunslingers of folklore rather than the true way societies functioned in places where state power was diluted or non-existent.

In the Old West it was not out of place for most men to be heavily armed at all times. But even if most men were armed and state law enforcement existed, why would there be a demand for gunslingers as providers of security and protection? The gunslinger provides solutions to several problems:

Firstly, he is willing to absorb the risks his employer would take trying to protect his material interests personally. He is more than a mere scarecrow; he is actively placing himself in the way of physical harm as a service to others. Yet the common revulsion against self-interest and the profit motive means he will not be called a hero for doing so, unlike his badge-bearing contemporaries of government.

Secondly, he is a specialist. The gunslinger, as his name implies, will probably be more skilled and accurate with a firearm than you are. From experience he will be more aware of, and more prepared to respond to, potentially dangerous persons or situations. His time will be spent focusing on security so his employer doesn’t have to.  In these ways the gunslinger’s presence provides his employer with the peace of mind to focus his energies and attentions on other more desirable and productive endeavours.

Finally, the gunslinger actually acts in part for the broader, law-abiding community. By deterring criminal actions, or engaging against and halting criminal activity, he is defending the interests of the community as a whole at no additional expense to the people within it. Conversely, the government can only attempt to provide such services by requisitioning resources from the community forcefully.

But is there a place for gunslingers in modern society?

Few countries and places in the world have gun laws relaxed enough to even allow their own citizens to own weapons, let alone brandish them in public. Fortunately for the people there is still private provision of security services, even in countries where the police are exceptionally well-funded and crime rates are relatively low. Clearly then the market not only demands private security provision, but actually needs it. And where better to observe this than South Africa?

The common reasons given for the failure of socialized policing to effectively protect citizens and property from criminals, and to apprehend said criminals, is that there is a dire lack of resources, training and personnel. More funds and voluntary help from the public are constantly proposed as the means to fighting the scourge of crime.

Yet these same labour and resource factors hardly seem to hamper provision of services by the private sector. The private security industry employs well over 400 000 people in South Africa and has been growing for decades. The government police employ over 190 000 people with a budget approaching R60 billion. Yet the ratio of private security agents to public police officers exceeds 3:1. Clearly then the accumulation of resources and trained personnel is a hollow excuse for why government policing is a failure. We must look at allocation of these factors to discover the problem.

The Austrian School of Economics explains that one of the fundamental reasons why socialized provision of goods and services cannot compare with market provision is that governments are simply not capable of efficiently co-ordinating and allocating capital, labour and resources.

Governments lack the incentives of market providers to: control costs, meet the needs of clients and be concerned with what the competition is doing in order to maintain profitability. Failure to manage these matters in the private sector leads to losses and, ultimately, insolvency.

Governmental bureaucracies, on the other hand, are prone to waste and graft and only have political edicts as incentive to be efficient. The operators of socialized agencies only have their superiors’ requirements to meet, not the consumers’, and never have to be concerned with competition, making a profit or performing under-budget all in the face of insolvency.

In short, because the revenue of bureaucracy is a matter of political allocation rather than customer allocation the incentives simply do not exist for government providers to perform nearly as efficiently and successfully as market providers.

Private providers offer a myriad of services and personnel to cater to the needs of clients and always have to be mindful of the quality of their service and the effectiveness of their pricing. From armed guards escorting valuables to unarmed guards patrolling property to armed responders who will reach your location in times of need within minutes, the private provision of protection is a vast network of specialized services that the government, even in wealthy nations, can scarcely compete with. And that is one of the secrets for success. As Ludwig von Mises relates: “The only source from which an entrepreneur’s profits stem is his ability to anticipate better than other people the future demand of the consumers.” It is simply amazing then that, even in the face of vastly superior resources and a collective presupposition that a primary role of government is protection, the private sector not only manages to outperform, but constantly outwit and outcompete the most formidable of competitors.

But where does all this leave the lone gunslinger? True to reputation, the wily opportunist can still find a niche or two in-between the state police and private security companies, but it is, however, in a realm beyond what the government would call “legal”. Take a drive through downtown Johannesburg and outside nearly every building where a business is in operation you’ll spot an inconspicuous-looking gentleman, usually dressed in a tracksuit, quietly keeping watch of passers-by. What does he keep beneath his baggy layers? It’s probably a good idea not to ask, but if society were more respectful of liberty he’d no doubt be holstered up confidently.

In the classic Charles Portis Western novel True Grit, a character observes that: “The civilized arts of commerce do not flourish there.” He was referring to territories outside the authority of the government. Contrary to this opinion, it is a miracle that commerce flourishes anywhere near where the government has influence, but it’s thanks in part to the willingness of men like the gunslinger to engage in the “civilized art” even though he’ll be branded as an outlaw for performing duties more worthy of the moniker “hero”.

Gareth B is an enthusiast of the Austro-libertarian tradition.  Presently resident in Johannesburg, he has also lived and worked in London and Chicago. 

  • J. Michael Oliver

    Great article. I wrote something along similar but less fleshed out vein as your great defense of private defense. Issue being the ownerless nature of stolen goods (stolen over years by the state) hence the open turf for pirates to “plunder” that ownerless class of assets. Pirateering in that sense should be legal. A form of returning stolen goods (stolen by State) to the private sector. Anyway, great article you wrote.

  • J. Michael Oliver

    http://mises.org/journals/lf/1977/1977_07.pdf

    That article in LF years ago entitled In defense of Pirateering. Forgot to include that link in my email to you.

  • Good blogging!